Thursday 30 August 2012

Timor Leste, the 5th Constitutional Government and the good governance template


By Martin Hardie
East Timorese newspaper Tempo Semanal published an article this week which has been distributed widely without any critical comment. The article claimed that the new Timorese Government represented an oligarchy. It also criticised the new government for its size and for the fact that it contained some brothers and sisters.
It is true that there has been criticism of the last Timorese Government for many reasons including corruption. It is also true that this same government established the Anti-Corruption Commission (KAK) which has led to some former ministers being investigated and in one case found guilty. The claims then that the government is too big and is because of this somehow by inference corrupt should not be left unanalysed.
In comparison with Australia the number of ministries is not large. Timor will have 17 ministries. Australia has 40. In Australia these 40 ministries are concentrated in the hands of only 21 people, that is power is more centralised. But this is not the real point.
In response to some of the comments that have been made on the article my colleague at Deakin University, professor Damien Kingsbury wrote on the ETAN mailing list:
However, if you understand them as being the equivalent of Ministers, Parliamentary Secretaries (same as vice-ministers in other parliamentary systems) and heads of departments with ministerial accountability, then this all starts to look much more like a normal parliamentary system.
If you compare Timor-Leste to, say South Australia (the population of SA is a little larger than T-L, but not much), you will see that SA has 15 ministers - only two less than Timor-Leste, but without the further responsibilities that come from running a country and not a state, e.g. defence, telecommunications, etc.
So maybe Timor-Leste does not have so many ministers after all. It just looks that way when a range of different individuals with different responsibilities and levels of responsibility are put in the same category.
There is a lot of merit in what Professor Kingsbury has said. The first thing is to put the criticisms about size into perspective. Timor will not have 55 Ministers but a mix of Ministers, Vice Ministers and Secretaries of State.
Tempo Semanal quoted the head of Luta Hamutuk NGO, Mericio Akara as saying:
“this new structure will not be effective and efficient, because too big and full of political interest. And full of political interest this structure will be more high cost, and I think every year government need more budgets to serve those Ministers. For us as a civil society better to invest more budget in the development sector rather then invest more budget in supporting new ministers.”
Underlying the logic of the criticism appears to be a logic which promotes an assumption that small government is always good. The argument seems to be that a big Cabinet is expensive and thus wasteful, that Timor is small and has many problems and that this waste can not be afforded.
This was the logic pushed by the United Nations during my time in Timor and implemented though a range of bodies such as the IMF, the World Bank and those NGO's that compose what is called 'civil society'. It appears that not much has changed and if anything critical analysis has all but disappeared. In its place we have criticisms of the new government which all seem to be drawn from the template of 'good governance' espoused by these organisations. Behind this template stands a policy which asserts that the primary function of the Third World state is to universalise private property rights. Small government, handing over its tasks to 'civil society' and the private sector to enable growth and the development of a competitive economy are all touted as the answer to Timor's problems. The latter, a competitive economy, is after all the centrepiece of the opposition party FRETILIN's alternate program for government.
Amongst all of this we have the criticism by some of the Timorese NGOs that argue the new Government structure is the result of political motivations. Underlying this is a logic that somehow government should not be political, or the result of political decisions but only economic ones. The becoming economic of government and of society is itself one of the hallmarks of neoliberalism. The new Timorese government is driven by political concerns – and so it should be. But this does not mean it is not concerned with waste, corruption or nepotism. What the government reflects is firstly the 'will of the people' expressed at the recent election – thus leaving one to wonder who the “us in civil society” mentioned by Akara in fact refers to. It also reflects the long standing practice of Xanana Gusmao to be as inclusive as possible, whether in resistance, the transition or in government. This is good politics and it is good politics that Timor needs along with the stability that the people seem to desire.
One could quite as easily characterise the new government as being more specialised and more focussed in that responsibilities appear to be more defined. Importantly the creation of the portfolio of President of the Council of Ministers, to be held by the former State Secretary Agio Pereira, and the appointment of Avelino Coelho as State Secretary for the Council of Ministers suggests that Prime Minister Gusmao is more than alive to the issue of how his Ministry will perform and the need to keep them accountable. Giving these portfolios to these two experienced and competent politicians can only be a sign of the increased focus upon what the NGO's call for: 'good governance'. This internal check on ministerial power combined with the work of Aderito Soares in the Anti-Corruption Commission can only be a good thing for the administration of government in Timor.
Another criticism levied at the new government is that of nepotism. Timor is still very much a tradition based society. It is not a society where tradition has yet been wiped away in the name of smoothing the space of the globe and making it safe for business. Having worked in both Timor and Arnhem Land I see many similarities in the manner in which society is organised. My point is that tradition and societal bonds in Timor are not just a replica of what we disingenuously call 'community' in Australia. Unlike Australia for example, Timor has community rather than a society of entrepreneurs and consumers. Bonds other than economic ones still exist between people. Family really is the basis of society. Other than that there is only a limited number of people with the skills needed to perform the tasks of government at this point in time. That skills base is further limited by the fact that they are divided up amongst the two principal political parties and nineteen others which contested the recent election. The reality is then that it is almost impossible not to find family members operating in similar areas. The criticisms of the government on this basis need to be put into this context and the manner in which Timorese society has been traditionally organised. To just blindly object to a Government on the basis that some people are related is really not far from saying that what you really want is a government that is not Timorese, in the sense that you want a government which does not reflect the composition of society, but one that reflects some template of 'good governance' promoted in a glossy World Bank pamphlet.
There is a further aspect to this criticism of nepotism that must not be left unremarked. The mantras of growth and building markets, such as those espoused by FRETILIN and some of the NGO's promote a vision of Timor as a fully fledged capitalist society. It is a long way from this at the moment. What private sector exists does so essentially because of government spending of one sort or another. It needs to be recalled that according to the theorists of neoliberalism, such as Hayek the natural state of people was to cooperate and as such competitive markets are not natural, they must be constructed. According to this theory the role of the state is to create the conditions for competition. Throughout history, including today how is this done? It is done by what Marx termed primitive accumulation, through what David Harvey calls accumulation by dispossession. Accumulation of land, money, resources and the dispossession of the people of the same things which include of course the public sector. My point is not to defend this, nor to defend any nepotism or corruption that may be occurring and which is occurring globally. Need I state the obvious and mention the current baking crisis, the austerity drives, or the dismantling of the public sector throughout the world by those that say government should be less political and more economic? Need I mention the growing global revolt against this? But here NGO's and others who want to promote this model, competitive markets, growth, the creation of a middle class and building markets cry foul when the process they champion might actually be taking place. If the NGOs are to be credible they can't have it both ways. They can't just roll out the global 'good governance' template, cry foul and apply it without analysis.
The situation reminds me of the thoughts of Paolo Freire in the opening pages of the Pedagogy of the Oppressed. The NGO's and others seem to suffer from “an absence of doubt”. Their positions are true positions and there is no doubt about that. The manner in which their message has gone viral is itself an example of Freire's “circle of certainty”. On the contrary it seems that the Government does not suffer from such an absence, it is acting politically in a political context and it appears to have given some thought to its previous mistakes and acted accordingly. As Freire might say the NGO's may actually need to confront their own position, to actually think and analyse the template they seem to be operating from. Confront, listen, unveil. Think rather than repeat the glib mantras of the custodians of a crumbling global system.
The new Timorese Government is not an oligarchy. For Aristotle an oligarchia designated the rule of the few for the few, rule that was exercised not by the best, but by bad men unjustly. Aristotle differentiated an oligarchy from an aristocracy where government by the few is vested in the best individuals. In the case of Timor the people decided the best individuals were those that formed the government led by Xanana. It may be an aristocracy but it is an elected one. An oligarchy also infers a ruling power bloc. What is apparent in Timor is that there are no consolidated permanent power blocs. Given the absence of power blocs in the oligarchic sense everything must be negotiated and this is the hallmark of Gusmao's style. Negotiation to the extent that there was even room for the opposition FRETILIN to be included in one way or another in this Government. Something which it seems that FRETILIN rejected. The task of negotiation and inclusion is one that the people and history have currently given to Xanana Gusmao. It is not an enviable or easy task and it is not one that is left to whim to undertake in a vacuum. The reality is that it is a political task and not one that conforms to a pre ordained template.

3 comments:

Wrick said...

It appears to me that the reference to Paolo Freire's 'absence of doubt' is just a pretentious, and (perhaps) polite way of saying that the author thinks that the NGO's rationale and critiques are 'dogmatic'. I would like to see the author address substantively, the particular issues and processes whereby the NGOs are trapped in this so called 'absence of doubt'. Perhaps they doubt more than the author.

Wrick said...

It appears to me that the reference to Paolo Freire's 'absence of doubt' is just a pretentious, and (perhaps) polite way of saying that the author thinks that the NGO's rationale and critiques are 'dogmatic'. I would like to see the author address substantively, the particular issues and processes whereby the NGOs are trapped in this so called 'absence of doubt'. Perhaps it is the author who is lacking in doubt, and that they 'doubt' more than the author.

Wrick said...

It appears to me that the reference to Paolo Freire's 'absence of doubt' is just a pretentious, and (perhaps) polite way of saying that the author thinks that the NGO's rationale and critiques are 'dogmatic'. I would like to see the author address substantively, the particular issues and processes whereby the NGOs are trapped in this so called 'absence of doubt'. Perhaps it is the author who is lacking in doubt, and that they 'doubt' more than the author.